Paul Collier, The Bottom Billion,
Reviewed by Erik
Paul Collier is an Africa-expert and a former director of the Development Research Group of the World Bank. At the core of the argument is his best-selling The Bottom Billion are four ‘traps’ that lock Africa into poverty: the conflict trap, the natural resource trap, the trap of being landlocked with bad neighbors, and the trap of bad governance in a small country. Compared to what used to be ‘development economics’, Collier represents a new economic genre.
Collier and colleagues Jeffrey Sachs and William Easterly – all former employees of the
Collier, Sachs, Easterly in fact belong to a new and different academic subfield, which we could call ‘development aid strategy’, which took over the position once occupied by development economics. Since no country has ever become wealthy through development aid (which is not per se an argument against aid), this development aid literature represents a problem. This literature contains little theory about what causes economic development besides aid, and – of particular importance – does not look at the strategies followed by today’s wealthy countries in their transition from poor to rich.
Compared to classical development economics Collier’s analysis is surprisingly static. Development economics typically postulated virtuous and vicious circles in the economy, not static traps. At the core of the virtuous circles of development lay a large division of labour, and the increasing returns and the technological change found in the industrial sector. Monoculture, diminishing returns, and increasing population pressure formed the core of the vicious circles.
Compared to classical development economics Collier’s view is not only static; he discusses ’traps’ which to a large extent are a result of poverty, not their root cause. Had he focused on an ’unemployment trap’, Collier would to some degree have been able to explain both the conflict trap and the bad governance trap. It can be argued that the most important raw material for the kind of conflicts from which
Paul Collier’s book The Bottom Billion appears after a long period of dominance of Washington Consensus policies in the
In this academic field of ‘development aid strategy’ a theoretical axis appeared between the development aid enthusiasts, exemplified by Jeffrey Sachs, the father of the Millennium Development Goals (The End of Poverty, 2005) on the one hand, and William Easterly who, briefly stated, is of the opinion that development aid does not work (The White Man’s Burden, 2006) on the other.
In this perspective Paul Collier’s Bottom Billion represents a kind of middle position between Sachs’ optimism and Easterly’s pessimism towards aid. However, all three have a past in important positions in Washington Institutions whose shock therapies caused so much damage to the economic structures of many poor countries. These authors do not come from a position of objectivity when they attempt to explain what went wrong.
Collier’s The Bottom Billion is heavily marked by the need to defend the past policies of the World Bank. The most salient misinterpretation of history is when Collier presents the successes of
It is also not obvious that Collier’s Bottom Billion uses the right criteria for measuring success. He implicitly sets up maximizing of world trade as a measurement of economic success. However, in many countries – Peru being just one example – globalization has lead to an impressive growth in exports, while real wages have been halved because manufacturing industry has virtually died out, and with it the labour unions that provided ‘stickiness’ to national wages.
In the tradition of the Washington Institutions Collier tends to reverse the directions of the arrows of causality, and even disregard co-evolution of economic structure and institutions. Banking and insurance were invented in cities with a particular economic structure. It is not that
To the economists of the Enlightenment ‘good governance’ or democracy seemed to be a product of a certain economic structure: diversified nations and city-states like the
Collier is right when he claims that high tariffs protecting national monopolies create corruption and high prices, but a solution to that problem would have been to encourage competition, not to kill industry as was done. Collier is also right when he flags the problem of small countries. Indeed, the minimum efficient size of a moderately wealth country has no doubt increased considerably. But this argument calls for regional economic integration, not for returning to raw material monoculture. As one 18th century economist put it: diversifying the economy away from dependence on agriculture cured the main ills of mankind: unemployment, superstition, poverty, and shortage of foreign exchange. Today’s failing states in
Collier does not analyze the mechanisms that got the presently wealthy nations out of poverty. From the Enlightenment on to 20th century Fascism, Nazism, Stalinism and Western Democracies: all development strategies were based on industrialization. When the Allies wanted to punish